Wednesday 8 July 2020

Big data suggests a difficult recovery in US jobs market

This is a summary of a column that appeared in the FT on 5 July 2020.

The full column appears here:

https://www.ft.com/content/607f24f5-71ed-452c-b68e-716145584e3d

Private data sources paint a detailed and worrying picture of the labour market after the Covid-19 shock

The latest US employment data showed that a marked recovery in the labour market continued into June, although only about a third of the jobs lost during the coronavirus shock have so far been regained.

The improvement is good news, but it should not be taken to imply that the labour market will rapidly return to normal, either in a macroeconomic sense, or in the distribution of job opportunities across the population.  A full return to pre-coronavirus jobs health will be long and difficult.

New data sources derived from private sector business activities, such as credit card flows and hiring websites, as well as Google searches, provide much richer sources of information about the behaviour of the labour market than have been available in previous recessions.

For example, on the macro side, Raj Chetty of Harvard University, a leading proponent of big data to improve economic research, has released an impressive website that provides daily information on US consumer spending and much else, using private sources.

Professor Chetty's data shows that after a surge in consumer activity up to mid May, the recovery has slowed down, with consumption recording a growth rate around 0.2 per cent a day up to the latest data on 24 June. The slowdown may well continue now that California, Texas, Florida and Arizona, together representing about 30 per cent of the US economy, are suffering from a worrying upsurge in Covid-19 cases.

On the micro side, the concentration of employment losses among unskilled workers in specific locations, with many permanently failed businesses, will become increasingly difficult to correct. The serious concerns about a deep-rooted scarring of the labour market, forcibly expressed by many Federal Reserve officials, would then be entirely justified.

The top three priorities to fix the jobs market in the US and elsewhere are virus policy, virus policy and virus policy. Focusing on general demand expansion won't work.


Tuesday 30 June 2020

The safe asset shortage after Covid-19

This is a summary of a column that appeared in the FT on 28 June 2020.

The full column appears here:

https://www.ft.com/content/b98078c0-6acc-43e6-929b-13883c211288

Demand for safe assets has far out-stripped supply since 2009 but the latest crisis may help redress the balance.


One of the long-term consequences of the 2008 financial crisis was a lack of safe assets that could be used by institutions to store their wealth, meet regulatory requirements and provide collateral to borrow additional funds. This problem has been identified as an important reason for low capital investment and the slow growth rate in the global economy in the past decade. It was also a prime cause of the European sovereign debt crisis, which peaked in 2012.

A silver lining from the Covid-19 shock is that the policy response may actually alleviate the safe-asset shortage, according to new research by Fulcrum economists (see table). That’s because it will leave a legacy of much higher government debt in the most advanced economies, including the US, which is the main global source of these assets.

Economists including Ricardo Caballero and Emmanuel Farhi have established that in some models a shortage of safe asset supply can result in a “safety trap” that affects the global economy. This is a close cousin of the “liquidity trap” that appears in many New Keynesian models. Because interest rates cannot fall enough to balance the supply and demand for safe assets, national income and wealth shrink to eliminate the excess demand for them.

The Covid-19 crisis will help because government debt in the US and other advanced economies is surging. Although central bank and private sector demand for safe assets may offset some of this extra supply, the overall effect may be to reduce the safe asset shortage for a while as the global economy recovers.


Wednesday 24 June 2020

Will public debt be a problem when the Covid-19 crisis is over?

This is a summary of a column that appeared in the FT on 21 June 2020.

The full column appears here:

https://www.ft.com/content/da150515-a5e9-4237-9b70-757dd958bf0d


There is unanimity about macro-economic policy for now, but not about the exit strategy


The major change in the major economies that is certain to follow the Covid-19 shock is a large and permanent rise in public debt ratios, including a rise in the US debt ratio to a new high for the series in the entire history of the Republic.

Macro-economists have been almost unanimous in agreeing that the stimulus packages to protect economic activity during the lockdowns have been appropriate, but an important debate is developing about the long term impact of higher debt ratios on the global economy.

Mainstream New Keynesian macro-economists (for example, Larry Summers and Paul Krugman) are not concerned about possible damage from higher public debt per se, and some appear to believe that this will actually be a positive, because it may offset the forces of secular stagnation. They also believe that debt servicing costs (ie bond yields) will probably remain below nominal GDP growth rates indefinitely, so high public debt and borrowing will be sustainable.

However, there is an important group of macro-economists, led by Ken Rogoff and John Cochrane, who believe that high debt ratios can lead to “runs” in public debt markets, even in advanced economies with their own central banks. They are therefore concerned that high and rising debt may result in financial calamity.

Although the New Keynesians are almost certainly right in the short and medium term, the debt school should not be ignored. A new strategy for the exit needs to be developed to mitigate these risks.

Tuesday 9 June 2020

Managing Covid debt mountains is a key task for the next decade

This is a summary of a column that appeared in the FT on 7 June 2020.

The full column appears here:

https://www.ft.com/content/a371909e-a3fe-11ea-92e2-cbd9b7e28ee6

Summary:

The recent surge in public debt in all of the major advanced economies is almost without precedent, even in wartime. In the US, for example, the government's financing requirement from April-June 2020 will reach $3tn, equal to 15% of this calendar year's GDP.

The IMF estimates that US government debt will exceed 130 per cent of GDP after the recession, more than 30 percentage points higher than a decade ago. These public debt mountains will need to be managed indefinitely, with little immediate prospect of reducing their size. The larger the scale, the greater the economic costs of debt mismanagement.

So far, there has been no panic about the sustainability of government debt, either in the US or elsewhere. This is a big success story for debt management policy. 

However, much of the funding has been accomplished by the sale of Treasury Bills, which has shortened the duration of the debt. This exposes the US government to increased interest rate risk, which can only be alleviated by extending the maturity of the debt over time.

In the 2010s, the US Treasury succeeded in extending duration, at a time when the Federal Reserve was attempting to shorten duration because it wanted to reduce long dated bond yields as part of its QE programme. This led to a tug-of-war between the two institutions, and their actions came close to negating each other entirely.

As the Treasury and the central bank are two parts of a single public sector balance sheet, it makes little sense for them to pull in entirely different directions. If secular stagnation deepens in coming years, as many expect, the Treasury should focus on shorter-term funding to help the Fed reduce bond yields and support economic growth. This would be likely to result in lower long term bond yields, and flatter yield curves, than those seen in the 2010s.

-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------

John Cochrane has commented on the FT column here:




Wednesday 3 June 2020

The effects of Covid-19 could deepen secular stagnation

This is a summary of a column that appeared in the FT on 31 May 2020.

The full column appears here:

https://www.ft.com/content/d60cdc40-9fec-11ea-b65d-489c67b0d85d

Summary:


When former US Treasury secretary Lawrence Summers delivered his famous address on the return of secular stagnation at the IMF in 2013, he revived interest in a Keynesian construct that had fallen into disuse since the 1940s. He argued that a chronic excess of savings, relative to capital investment, may be developing in the global economy, forcing long-term interest rates down and threatening a persistent shortage of demand.

Mr Summers’ warnings have proven largely justified in the last 7 years. He now believes that the COVID-19 crisis may deepen secular stagnation, because risk aversion in the private sector will increase permanently, leading to more precautionary savings by households, and less investment by businesses. As he puts it, “just in case will replace just in time”.

A permanent state in which the equilibrium nominal interest rate throughout the developed world is at or below the central bank policy rate is, to put it mildly, really worrying.  Traditional monetary policy would become impossible, without major policy reforms to change the situation. There are three possible consequences of this.

The first is that the world could be stuck at zero. All the advanced economies may follow the example of Japan since 2016, with interest rates across the entire yield curve stuck at zero, and fiscal policy battling against a continuous rise in government debt ratios. For asset markets, this would represent a low-return world, with demand management becoming increasingly hamstrung in recurring recessions.

The second could involve permanent fiscal stimulus and rising debt. By reversing the trend decline in interest rates, this policy may result in an immediate period of negative returns for both bonds and equities.

And the third could give us very negative interest rates. Negative rate policy could only succeed if pursued aggressively, taking policy rates to minus 3 per cent, or even lower, in recessions. By extending the decades-long downward trend in interest rates, this approach would probably prolong high returns from both bonds and equities. 

The political feasibility of these extremely radical fiscal and monetary policy changes seems highly questionable. But if Mr Summers is right about the deepening of secular stagnation, such reforms might be needed to avoid Japanese-style deflation in Europe, and even the US.




Friday 29 May 2020

US household savings surge to new highs as consumers become more cautious


This is a summary of an article by Gavyn Davies that appeared in the FT on 23 May 2020. The full article can be found here:

https://www.ft.com/content/fffa1302-99ba-11ea-adb1-529f96d8a00b


Several aspects of the recession that has started in the US and other major economies are simply a much larger version of a “normal” recession, but there is one major difference from the past. Because fiscal policy has reacted so rapidly to the collapse in output, household disposable income has been shielded almost entirely from the weakening in the labour market, and the enormous drop in the consumption of discretionary goods and services has been accompanied by a jump in the savings ratio.

In the US, for example, household savings may exceed 20% of disposable income in 2020 Q2, about three times the level seen before the virus lockdowns began.

Although savings will certainly diminish as the lockdowns on household behaviour are eased, there may be a residual of precautionary savings which remain stubbornly high.

A complete withdrawal of the fiscal stimulus before consumer risk appetite has returned to normal will slow the recovery and keep unemployment above the natural rate for several more quarters. As Federal Reserve Chairman Jay Powell has argued, more fiscal support may be needed to promote a full recovery in the economy.

Update: April data show even larger surge than expected 







Tuesday 19 May 2020

Why the US unemployment surge is so much worse than in Europe


This is a summary of an article by Gavyn Davies that appeared in the FT on 19 May 2020. The full article can be found here:


The flexibility of the US labour market is often viewed as one of the main reasons for the long term success of the American economy, compared to that of Europe, both in terms of asset market returns and growth in potential GDP. However, the policy responses to the labour market shocks caused by the supply lockdowns to control Covid-19 may change these perceptions.

Saturday 16 May 2020

Negative interest rates and government bond curves

In the past few weeks, nominal interest rates at the very front end of the US yield curve have shifted marginally into negative territory for the first time. Although negative policy rates have become commonplace in both Japan and Eurozone since the mid 2010s, and have extended to longer dated bonds, this phenomenon is still seen as a complete novelty in US markets.

With breakeven inflation rates generally remaining well anchored on the Fed's 2 per cent inflation target, and the FOMC unanimously having determined only last October that negative policy rates were still undesirable, investors had not, until lately, seen any reason why the US central bank would follow the ECB and the BoJ into negative territory. But the COVID-19 economic crisis may be changing that.

Thursday 7 May 2020

Bank of England's V-shaped scenario differs from the Fed's view

The Bank of England's Monetary Policy Report for May shows an economic "scenario" that depicts the "worst UK recession for 300 years". This sounds extremely alarming, and indeed it is. But in fact the MPC has probably chosen the least-bad path for output that is feasible in present circumstances. As many independent economists have warned, a completely unbiased central projection would have been considerably worse, especially after the trough of the recession is reached.

New blog on global macro starts today

Welcome to a new blog on global macro-economics, focused on the interaction between the world economy, policy and markets. The content will mainly be written by Gavyn Davies, Chairman of Fulcrum Asset Management, drawing frequently on the work of the Fulcrum economics research team.

Tuesday 5 May 2020

After lockdowns, economic sunlight or a long hard slog?

Equities imply that economic activity will swiftly return to previous peaks


The strong recovery in global financial confidence caused the S&P 500 index to rebound 13 per cent in April, leaving US share prices only 9 per cent below their levels at the end of last year. This may seem puzzling, given the slim prospect that a vaccine against the virus, or effective treatments, will become available soon.

The surge appears to rest on the pattern shown in gross domestic product forecasts from the big investment banks (see below), which is mainly driven by the expected path for supply shutdowns.